6 resultados para schedule of cleanings
em Repositório digital da Fundação Getúlio Vargas - FGV
Resumo:
Concomitantemente à produção de etanol, a partir da fermentação de diferentes matérias-primas (cana-de-açúcar, beterraba, milho, trigo, batata, mandioca), produz-se a vinhaça. A vinhaça da cana-de-açúcar é gerada na proporção média de 12 litros para cada litro de etanol. O Brasil é o maior produtor mundial de cana-de-açúcar (570 milhões de toneladas, em 2009) com a produção de 27 bilhões de litros/ano de etanol, no ciclo 2009/2010, basicamente para fins carburantes, e, portanto, a quantidade de vinhaça produzida é da ordem de 320 bilhões de litros/ano. Dentre as possíveis soluções para a destinação da vinhaça, tais como: concentração, tratamento químico e biológico ou produção de biomassa, é sua aplicação no solo a forma mais usual de disposição. No entanto, sua aplicação no solo não pode ser excessiva nem indiscriminada, sob pena de comprometer o ambiente e a rentabilidade agrícola e industrial da unidade sucroalcooleira. A necessidade de medidas de controle sobre a aplicação de vinhaça no solo do Estado de São Paulo, que concentra a produção de 60% do etanol produzido no Brasil, levou à elaboração da Norma Técnica P4.231, em 2005. A constatação do cumprimento dos itens desta Norma é uma das ações do agente fiscalizador, no monitoramento da geração e destinação da vinhaça pelos empreendimentos produtores de etanol. Os itens 5.7.1 e 5.7.2, desta Norma, tornam obrigatório o encaminhamento à CETESB (Companhia Ambiental do Estado de São Paulo), para fins de acompanhamento e fiscalização, até o dia 02 de abril de cada ano, o PAV (Plano de Aplicação de Vinhaça). Com o intuito de proporcionar melhor entendimento da Norma P4.231, contribuir para otimização de sua aplicabilidade e melhoria e perceber a realidade prática da aplicação da vinhaça, foram analisados PAVs protocolados na Agência Ambiental de Piracicaba, licenças concedidas, processos de licenciamento e realizadas vistorias a campo. Conclui-se que a Norma P4.231 representa um avanço no gerenciamento do uso da vinhaça no Estado de São Paulo, por disciplinar a disposição de vinhaça no solo, tornando obrigatórios: demarcações de áreas protegidas e núcleos populacionais, caracterização de solo e da vinhaça, doses máximas a serem aplicadas, estudos da geologia e hidrogeologia locais, monitoramento das águas subterrâneas, impermeabilização de tanques e dutos. Estabelece critérios a serem obedecidos por lei, e todos são condutas de boas práticas de proteção ao meio, que repercutem em maior rentabilidade agrícola e industrial. A Norma P4.231 é bem elaborada, complexa e extensa, o que a torna de difícil execução. Para facilitar sua aplicabilidade, sugere-se o estabelecimento de um cronograma de prioridades: impermeabilização dos tanques e dutos, drenos testemunha com funcionamento otimizado e boa caracterização do que está sendo aplicado, se vinhaça pura ou se misturada a águas residuárias. Das oito empresas deste estudo, apenas quatro (as maiores) vêm protocolando os PAVs com regularidade, desde 2005. As informações apresentadas foram incompletas e, em alguns casos, precárias. Mesmo com lacunas, os dados fornecidos, desde o início da obrigatoriedade do PAV, foram de utilidade para esboçar o perfil da atividade sucroalcooleira na região estudada.
Resumo:
We investigate the efficiency of equal sacrifice tax schedules in an economy which primitives are exactly those in Mirrlees (1971): a continuum of individuals with identical preferences defined over consumption and leisure who differ with respect to their labor market productivity. Using a separable specification for preferences we derive the minimum equal sacrifice allocation and recover the tax schedule that implements it. The separable specification allows us to use the methodology developed by Werning (2007b) to check whether the schedule is efficient, that is, whether there is no alternative tax schedule that raises more revenue while delivering less utility to no one. We find that inefficiency does not arise for most parametrizations we use to approximate the US economy. For the few cases for which inefficiency does arise, it does so only for very high levels of income and marginal tax rates.
Resumo:
Recent advances in dynamic Mirrlees economies have incorporated the treatment of human capital investments as an important dimension of government policy. This paper adds to this literature by considering a two period economy where agents are di erentiated by their preferences for leisure and their productivity, both private information. The fact that productivity is only learnt later in an agent's life introduces uncertainty to agent's savings and human capital choices and makes optimal the use of multi-period tie-ins in the mechanism that characterizes the government policy. We show that optimal policies are often interim ine cient and that the introduction of these ine ciencies may take the form of marginal tax rates on labor income of varying sign and educational policies that include the discouragement of human capital acquisition. With regards to implementation, state-dependent linear taxes implement optimal savings, while human capital policies may require labor income taxes that depend directly on agents' schooling.
Resumo:
Secure property rights are considered a key determinant of economic development. However, the evaluation of the causal effects of land titling is a difficult task. The Brazilian government through a program called "Papel Passado" has issued titles, since 2004, to over 85,000 families and has the goal to reach 750,000. Furthermore, another topic in Public Policy that is crucial to developing economies is income generation and child labor force participation. Particularly, in Brazil, about 5.4 million children and teenagers between 5 and 17 years old are still working. This thesis examines the direct impact of securing a property title on income and child labor force participation. In order to isolate the causal role of ownership security, this study uses a comparison between two close and very similar communities in the City of Osasco case (a town with 650,000 people in the São Paulo metropolitan area). One of them, Jardim Canaã, was fortunated to receive the titles in 2007, the other, Jardim DR, given fiscal constraints, only will be part of the program schedule in 2012, and for that reason became the control group. Also, this thesis also aims to test if there is any relationship between land title and happiness. The estimates suggest that titling results in a substantial decrease of child labor force participation, increase of income and happiness for the families that received the title compared to the others.
Resumo:
In an economy which primitives are exactly those in Mirrlees (1971), we investigate the efficiency of labor income tax schedules derived under the equal sacrifice principle. Starting from a given government revenue level, we use Werning’s (2007b) approach to assess whether there is an alternative tax schedule to the one derived under the equal sacrifice principle that raises more revenue while delivering less utility to no one. For our preferred parametrizations of the problem we find that inefficiency only arises at very high levels of income. We also show how the multipliers of the Pareto problem may be extracted from the data and used to find the implicit marginal social weights associated with each level of income.
Resumo:
Lucas (2000) estimates that the US welfare costs of inflation are around 1% of GDP. This measurement is consistent with a speci…c distorting channel in terms of the Bailey triangle under the demand for monetary base schedule (outside money): the displacement of resources from the production of consumption goods to the household transaction time à la Baumol. Here, we consider also several new types of distortions in the manufacturing and banking industries. Our new evidences show that both banks and firms demand special occupational employments to avoid the inflation tax. We de…ne the concept of ”the foat labor”: The occupational employments that are aflected by the in‡ation rates. More administrative workers are hired relatively to the bluecollar workers for producing consumption goods. This new phenomenon makes the manufacturing industry more roundabout. To take into account this new stylized fact and others, we redo at same time both ”The model 5: A Banking Sector -2” formulated by Lucas (1993) and ”The Competitive Banking System” proposed by Yoshino (1993). This modelling allows us to characterize better the new types of misallocations. We …nd that the maximum value of the resources wasted by the US economy happened in the years 1980-81, after the 2nd oil shock. In these years, we estimate the excess resources that are allocated for every speci…c distorting channel: i) The US commercial banks spent additional resources of around 2% of GDP; ii) For the purpose of the firm foating time were used between 2.4% and 4.1% of GDP); and iii) For the household transaction time were allocated between 3.1% and 4.5 % of GDP. The Bailey triangle under the demand for the monetary base schedule represented around 1% of GDP, which is consistent with Lucas (2000). We estimate that the US total welfare costs of in‡ation were around 10% of GDP in terms of the consumption goods foregone. The big di¤erence between our results and Lucas (2000) are mainly due to the Harberger triangle in the market for loans (inside money) which makes part of the household transaction time, of the …rm ‡oat labor and of the distortion in the banking industry. This triangle arises due to the widening interest rates spread in the presence of a distorting inflation tax and under a fractionally reserve system. The Harberger triangle can represent 80% of the total welfare costs of inflation while the remaining percentage is split almost equally between the Bailey triangle and the resources used for the bank services. Finally, we formulate several theorems in terms of the optimal nonneutral monetary policy so as to compare with the classical monetary theory.